How Should Higher Education Be Financed?

Plus! Accredited Investors; Gambling on Gambling; Price Discrimination; In Play; Even More Product Convergence; Diff Jobs

In this issue:

Today's issue of The Diff is brought to you by our sponsors, Intercom.

How Should Higher Education Be Financed?

Normally, if there's a question about paying for something that's phrased in the passive voice, it's eliding the true question, which is more accurately phrased as "How should you pay for my..?" But education is a special case: it's extremely expensive, with direct costs totaling $702bn in 2020-21 (as in, that figure does not include the opportunity cost of students' time, teachers' talents, and the fixed assets schools occupy). It's also a case with positive externalities, both from practical work—a country without any civil engineers can't build or mantain bridges—and more abstract ones. And, critically for the who-pays-how question, the people attending college do not personally have the resources to drop five figures per annum on a degree, but, because of their age, will be benefiting from that education over a longer period than someone who works for a while to save up enough to pay for college in cash.

So higher education must be paid for through some combination of students’ earnings, parents' savings, school subsidies, government subsidies, loans, and special deals with employers. Unfortunately, all of these lead to problems one way or another. For example, if we're requiring everyone to fund their own education upfront, either directly through they're own earnings or indirectly through their parents', then we're setting up a system with an education shortage among people who didn't choose the right parents, or among people whose post-graduation incomes will be higher than their pre-graduation incomes.[1] Conversely, if everyone's education were free, then there wouldn’t be a good way to determine a) which specific programs ought to have different prices because of the supply and demand for that kind of credential, b) whether particular people might be better-served by spending their time in different ways, or c) when we're allocating too much of society's resources to education, in the aggregate.

The possibility of spending "too much" on education is itself mostly missing from debates over how, and how much, to fund it. But it ought to be a genuine concern. Not just because college graduates have higher incomes, and student loan borrowers' spending patterns do not indicate much financial distress on average, but because it's possible for overall education spending to be too high (even aside from the question of whether higher education spending is redistribution towards the highest earners). There are a few failure modes here: obviously it's a problem if people are literally starving or freezing because they're too busy studying. But there are more subtle issues:

Meanwhile, the strength of the college bundle is weakening. College has always been a mix of different services—there's instruction, sure, but there's also socializing with a group of peers who've been selected as intellectual peers, a certain ideological environment, a chance for reinvention, the benefit of a prestigious brand name. And college, like a music festival, is a chance to party with lots of young people who don't have to wake up particularly early the next morning.

18-year-olds still have a lot to figure out, so there's an argument for giving them some time to do that in a low-stress environment. There's also a counterargument that a low-stress environment is the worst way to figure out what actually matters to you. When you're barely getting by, the way you spend your next free hour or next available dollar is going to be a lot more thoughtful. And figuring yourself out is a gradual, perhaps lifelong process, albeit with some breaks here and there.[4] A low-stakes environment where it's almost impossible to fail is, if anything, a break from the hard question of what to do with your life.

College works well for many people, but college-for-all as a default clearly isn't working in the aggregate. Nationwide college completion rates have been stable in the low 60s since 2015, and the minimum required coursework doesn't appear to have gotten much tougher over time. The kind of college experience that drives average outcomes is still available, but it's opt-in for students who choose challenging coursework, do the required reading, and don't outsource their homework to essay mills and LLMs.

Even if the current system doesn't work very well, it's not as if all the talent involved is wasted. A lot of it is misallocated. So, some policy proposals:

You can't force employers to ignore college degrees, and if you subsidize hiring non-graduates you create all sorts of perverse incentives.[5] You can shift the norm, of course: any time someone requires a college degree, they're implicitly claiming that they're worse at evaluating talent than admissions offices. That ought to be at least mildly embarrassing, at least for any company that argues that employee talent is crucial to their competitive advantage. The systems above are leakier than what we currently have, at least in terms of ensuring that everyone can enroll in college at 18. But that's also a good setup, because they're explicit about what can be done to increase access: instead of making education a national issue that can be nudged slighty through individual action, it becomes amenable to personally coaching people through the nuances of loans, or of subsidizing education through hiring decisions. There is a place for higher education, but warped financial incentives have put it in very much the wrong place right now. Fiddling with those, normalizing the fiddling, and de-normalizing four-years-for-all won't fix everything, but it will change the overall trajectory in the right direction.


  1. That's a problem in both directions, incidentally: a big piece missing from the education discourse is the opportunity cost for students—it's counterintuitive that any four-year degree, regardless of topic, is a better option than any alternative. The higher someone’s pre-college income, the more worthwhile it is to think carefully about whether college is the best way to spend the next four years. ↩︎

  2. In both cases, these are useful models for starting to reason rigorously about aggregate behavior. If you don't assume some kind of rationality, you can't say much at all about the economy. But these premises are taken too literally, too often. ↩︎

  3. One reason people get specific degrees is that there are particular jobs they really, really want that absolutely require those degrees as a condition of entry. If you're considering or pursuing such a credential for that reason, know this: your view of the job, its prestige, etc. is out-of-date. That perception formed when the job was newer, cooler, and less institutionalized, and has been decaying ever since then. When undergrads read Liar's Poker in the 90s and decided to become mortgage bond traders, they didn't know that the phones were being thrown less and the lunches were already less gluttonous. Someone who watched The Social Network and decided to start a startup incidentally chose to build one in a world where the big platforms had mostly been built, and where growth was less a matter of creating a viral hit and more one of optimizing ad spend on somebody else's now-impregnable viral hit. And if you have a counterexample, it may be a fake counterexample—if your law school professor really acts just like Professor Kingsfield, it's probably because your professor watched The Paper Chase, too, just like wiretaps revealed that mafiosos all started talking like Mario Puzo characters after The Godfather came out. It's not that there is no 'there' there, there was just a different there there back then. ↩︎

  4. If you figure out your true meaning in life right after having kids, for example, that's too bad, unless it turns out that the real meaning of life is being a good parent for the next couple decades. This applies, albeit usually to a lesser degree, for finding oneself after undertaking commitments incompatible with that new enlightenment. ↩︎

  5. Including a reverse-sheepskin effect, where it pays to finish coursework, get an excellent GPA, and refuse to take that last required class before you can be awarded a diploma. ↩︎

A Word From Our Sponsors

Intercom is a complete, AI and human customer service platform—and the only platform to combine a help desk, AI chatbot, and proactive support tools.

It also comes equipped with a fully featured inbox, ticketing, help center, and messenger, making it not only complete—but also the most powerful support platform. On the planet.

Elsewhere

Accredited Investors

The SEC has a new edition of their periodic reporting on accredited investor status. The rules defining accredited investors were set in absolute dollar terms, and haven't changed in a long time—in 1983, 1.8% of US households qualified for accredited investor status, but now it's 18.5%, and the SEC helpfully projects that in the year 2052, 64% of households will be accredited investors, just because of inflation.

One of the cases for inflation is that it's a way to continuously adjust some quantities, like wages, that are otherwise sticky. It was almost certainly not part of the SEC's original reasoning, but it works well in this case: the amount of information available to investors has exploded; effectively no one outside of the finance industry knew what a hedge fund was in the early 1980s, but that knowledge is more common today. And the ceiling on sophistication, for both retail and institutional investors, has gone way up. At the same time, the complexity of products available has also expanded. As with higher education, fixed rules don't work as well as flexible ones, and given the growing incentive to market investment vehicles that are inappropriate, or at least high-fee and tax-inefficient, means that a switch from an income test ("you can afford to lose it if you don't know what you're doing") to a hybrid income- and exam-based one ("You know what you're getting into, or at least can afford to be wrong") works better.

Gambling on Gambling

A wise short-seller once argued that company management should be delighted to talk to shorts, since they're the only investors in the world who are guaranteed to be future buyers of the stock. Jim Chanos, who recently announced plans to shut down his longstanding short-focused hedge fund, has flipped to long the sports betting companies ($, FT). But it's very much a short-seller's long thesis: the bet is that the average gambler is much more willing to lose money than is rational for them, so DraftKings and the like actually have a solid business. It's a long position, sure, but that basically describes the view Chanos bet his entire career on.

(The Diff briefly covered the wind-down of Chanos' fund ($), and how it exemplifies the two sides of the hedge fund balance sheet. The Diff also covered the evolution of DraftKings' economics ($) a few days prior.)

Price Discrimination

Apple is now allowing apps to offer conditional pricing, i.e. discounting app A based on paying for app B. One of the forces that drives general technology consolidation is that single vendors win over multiple vendors—if there's just one point of contact for every product in a category, it's easier to keep track of (and the company offering it can provide a better service knowing that their customers will stick around longer). What pushes back against that is that eventually, people are paying a high minimum price, mostly for features they don't need or use. Creating tools for bundling makes it easier for individual products to opportunistically fit into both categories: a point solution for one set of customers, and part of a comprehensive suite for others.

In Play

US Steel will be acquired by Nippon Steel for a total of over $14bn, with the equity component of the deal at a 57% premium to the value of the unsolicited offer they got from Cleveland Cliffs four months ago. It's a good illustration of how companies are more likely to be acquired once they're clearly being shopped around, whether or not the original bidder ends up being the buyer. When a company gets an offer, or there's a rumor, two things happen quickly: first, all of their competitors refresh whatever M&A analyses they've done (probably with the help of fee-seeking bankers) to make sure they don't miss out on buying some useful cost synergies or strategic positioning. At the same time, the shareholder base of the target company turns over rapidly, as arbitrageurs buy and other holders realize windfall profits and sell. The result is that there are more bidders, and more shareholders are happy to sell to the highest bidder.

Even More Product Convergence

Robinhood's original pitch was that, however small an investor you were, you could get started with them and grow from there. If a $10 commission meant losing 10% of your account's value on either side of the trade, both you and your broker would be dubious about doing business together. Robinhood was fine with it. If you wanted to own shares of a company whose share price exceeded the total value of your account, that, too, was something Robinhood was happy to handle with fractional shares. But eventually, Robinhood reached the same conclusiont hat everyone else in finance does: it's nice to have lots of small customers, but the unit economics are much, much better from having the same dollar value controlled by fewer, bigger customers. So they're targeting bigger accounts ($, WSJ). There's a cycle in the brokerage business, where older companies target bigger customers, creating an opportunity for a newer business with cheap marketing and (ideally) low operating costs to compete at the low end. Unless they do a catastrophic job of selecting clients, they eventually end up with high net worth customers simply because of compound interest and the high dispersion of retail returns. At that point, it makes more sense to cater to those customers. And the cycle begins again.

Diff Jobs

Companies in the Diff network are actively looking for talent. See a sampling of current open roles below:

Even if you don't see an exact match for your skills and interests right now, we're happy to talk early so we can let you know if a good opportunity comes up.

If you’re at a company that's looking for talent, we should talk! Diff Jobs works with companies across fintech, hard tech, consumer software, enterprise software, and other areas—any company where finding unusually effective people is a top priority.